
RECOMMENDED READING
Whenever Congress debates raising the minimum wage, policymakers reflexively turn to economists for advice, and nearly all economists, regardless of their ideological orientation, say with unyielding conviction that a higher minimum wage will produce higher unemployment. The only difference between conservative and liberal economists is that they latter say the increase will be negligible, but at least the remaining low-income workers will earn a bit more.
But nearly all economists are wrong. Raising the minimum wage would not increase unemployment; it would increase living standards for low-income workersâand, critically, it would boost overall U.S. productivity growth.
Economists typically get this wrong because they are devotees of the sacrosanct theory that prices make the world go around. As John Kenneth Galbraith once wrote, âan economist without a price system is like a priest without a divine being.â The cardinal sin for any economist is to support policies that would artificially distort pricesâin this case the price for laborâbecause according to the received economic wisdom, it would distort labor markets and lead to less economic welfare, not more.
But that assumes labor markets are perfect and there is only one equilibrium price for laborânamely, that which markets generate through supply and demand. That is demonstrably untrue, however. In a noble heresy against established thinking, economist Elvio Accinelli and colleagues have found that labor markets can be in different states of equilibriumâwith either a high level of innovation, skills, and wages, or a âpoverty trapâ of underinvestment in capital equipment, and low skills and wages. Sadly, it is the latter state that best describes the U.S. economy today, with the real minimum wage one-third lower than it was in the late 1960s (and almost half when factoring in the growth of median income). A higher minimum wage thus would be like a defibrillator for an economic heart that is no longer pumping right.
The second mistake many economists make in opposing a higher minimum wage is assuming employment rates are set at the micro level, like demand for milk or basketball shoes. They are likely to remind you with haughty exasperation that it is a âfundamental law of economicsâ that when the price of anything increases, demand will decrease. But the truth is that demand for labor, unlike demand for consumer products, is set largely at the macro level. If the Federal Reserve lowers interest rates, then demand for labor increases until we reach full employment. If fiscal policy is loose (e.g., with increases in government spending or tax cuts), then labor demand goes up.
Some economists also succumb to the âlump of laborâ fallacy, believing that if a job is lostâbecause of automation or a higher minimum wageâthen it is gone for good. The Congressional Budget Office fell into that trap earlier this month when it issued an analysis arguing that a higher minimum wage would increase employersâ production costs, and: âEmployers would consequently produce fewer goods and services, and as a result, they would tend to reduce their employment of workers at all wage levels.â
But if a company lays off workers because a higher minimum wage forces them to raise prices, then the remaining workers would be making more moneyâand they wouldnât bury it; they would spend it, which would create jobs.
Besides, the real minimum wage has been much higher in the past than it is today, and unemployment was still low. In 1968, it was around $12.25 in todayâs dollarsâalmost 70 percent higher than the current rate of $7.25âyet the unemployment rate was around 3.5 percent. Critics also claim a higher minimum wage would boost youth unemployment, but there was effectively no correlation at all between youth unemployment rates and the real minimum wage in the 50-plus years from 1968 to 2020. (The correlation coefficient was a miniscule 0.03, to be exact.)
The reality is that a higher minimum wage wouldnât increase unemploymentâbut it would boost productivity growth, for the simple reason that when the price of labor is high, the return on investments in labor-saving technology is higher. Often referred to as the âWebb effect,â the most persuasive evidence suggests that a higher wage floor leads to higher levels of capital investment. As one study concluded, âif the federal government raises the minimum wage, employers in some sectors may expedite the adoption of automated equipment and new technology to increase labor productivity.â
But wonât that lead to fewer jobs? No. The evidence is abundantly clear that higher productivity is not associated with fewer jobs overall. Thatâs because higher productivity leads to higher wages and lower price increases, which produces more spending.
There are legitimate questions as to whether the minimum wage should go to $15 or $12 per hour, or whether it should be adjusted to the regional cost of living. But on the basic issue of whether it should increase, policymakers shouldnât let themselves be distracted by a faulty analysis that rests on the dusty altar of price theory.
Recommended Reading
Jobs Americans Would Do
A more productive conversation about raising workersâ wages
A Labor Shortage Is a Great Problem to Have
Todayâs jobs report from the Bureau of Labor Statistics shows the unemployment rate continuing to hold close to its lowest level in 70 years, despite a slight uptick last month. This might seem Read more…
How to Raise the Minimum Wage, If You Must
Let’s peg the federal minimum wage to state median wages.